Category: Housing and Transportation Policy

  • Historical Context for U.S. Housing Policy Part 2: Public Housing

    Historical Context for U.S. Housing Policy Part 2: Public Housing

    The US public housing program originated in 1937, as one of the last pieces of legislation included in the New Deal. Like the HOLC and the FHA, public housing was initially aimed at solving the problem of widespread homelessness and housing insecurity created by the Great Depression. Public housing had the additional virtue of allowing for large-scale construction in a single place, and was therefore wielded as a tool for infrastructure growth and jobs creation. For this reason, many of the initial public housing developments were located near, and in service of, major construction projects. Public housing projects were managed and run by local housing authorities but funded entirely through federal capital grants. Rent collections from tenants were expected to cover operating expenses and future maintenance. 

    From the outset, political compromise and concessions created challenges for public housing. Rigorous lobbying from real estate interests and their conservative constituencies—mostly Southern Democrats—led to the agreement that public housing must be markedly inferior to private developments, both aesthetically and functionally. To ensure that these public developments would not compete in the private market, the federal government set low ceilings on construction costs. Additionally, public housing projects were blatantly segregated based on race; developments preserved for White people were located closer to job sites and were given more funding to attract skilled workers. The Public Housing Authorities (PHAs) in White developments enforced strict standards for residents, ensuring that they maintained orderly living spaces and stayed out of trouble with the law. For White people, the early years of public housing, though not luxurious, were a far cry from the current perception of derelict high-rises, ridden with crime. 

    Following the end of World War II, and the gains in White, middle-class homeownership generated by the G.I. bill, Congress commenced a period of accelerated public housing construction—set into action by the Housing Act of 1949. As generous mortgages and federal subsidies built the suburbs, low-income Americans faced a shortage of affordable housing in urban areas. To address this problem, the 1949 Act authorized the construction of 810,000 public housing units over the next six years. It was during this time that many of the high-rise developments—such as the infamous Pruit-Igoe in St. Louis—were built. These buildings are famously deficient: devoid of decoration or amenity; set back from the streetscape; shoddy construction and dull architecture. Many current advocates argue, however, that the widespread publicization of public housing failures presented an inaccurate and grossly exaggerated account. They further argue that many developed units were smaller—mostly row houses and smaller apartments—and that the image of unsightly high-rises contributes to a stigma against public housing. 

    Stigmas aside, public housing has never been socially desirable. With the growth of FHA-insured mortgages, those who could afford to move did so (except for Black Americans), often to suburban developments. This meant that public housing residents gradually became poorer and less White. The median income of tenants fell consistently in the decades after public housing’s conception. The promulgation of upper income limits and the eviction of middle-class tenants meant that by 1970, most tenants earned less than 20% of the national median. Public housing gradually became synonymous with lower-class, harboring pockets of concentrated poverty. In addition, a Circuit Court of Appeals had ruled in 1935 that the federal government does not have the power to acquire local property through eminent domain. A lack of federal control afforded localities ample room to keep public housing out of desirable areas—whether that be by opting-out of funding for construction altogether, choosing construction sites near environmental hazards, or strategically locating sites in accordance with racial segregation.

    In 1973, President Nixon issued a moratorium on the construction of new public housing, calling it “monstrous, depressing places–rundown, overcrowded, crime-ridden”. Nixon effectively declared public housing a policy failure, prompting Congress to refuse to provide sufficient funding for upkeep and modernization.

    This top-down declaration quickly morphed into consensus. In 1993, the federal government launched the HOPE VI to demolish and redevelop more than 150,000 public housing units. HOPE VI rode a wave of changes to the policing system known as the “broken windows theory” which argues that higher quality living environments, in which amenities are durable and repairs are made promptly (repairing broken windows, for example) reduce crime and engender socially-positive behaviors. In this vein, HOPE VI sought to replace distressed public housing with mixed-income developments with more aesthetically minded features designed to blend in with surrounding developments. Additionally, HOPE VI buildings had shallower subsidies and stricter tenant eligibility that took into consideration poor credit histories, the existence of a criminal record, and other applicant characteristics. HOPE VI marked the end of highly-concentrated public developments. 
    There are a few enduring themes to keep in mind when considering the history of the public housing program. The first is the question of concentrated poverty and its externalities. Even though the central aim of the public housing program has always been to serve low-income and housing-insecure Americans, it has long been understood that homogeneously low-income developments are harmful to the interest of residents. Concentrated poverty gives rise to more violence, poorly maintained facilities, and other negative forces that are endemic to poverty. The tension for policymakers is therefore between prioritizing the neediest citizens and improving life-outcomes for those served. A second and related tension has to do with a leniency in tenant behavior. While leniency—poor behavior and late payments—strikes many as the morally charitable stance, it can also give rise to harsher conditions. Public housing has operated, in effect, as a safety net for low-income Americans, and thus has had to tolerate many of the adverse behaviors that come with living in entrenched poverty. If unruly residents were given the boot, as would be needed to maintain an orderly environment, where would they go?

  • Housing Policy in the United Kingdom

    Housing Policy in the United Kingdom

    Why Compare the United States with the United Kingdom?

    The United Kingdom is currently experiencing many of the same housing challenges as the United States, such as similar trends in homeownership among generations currently coming of age, unaffordable rents, and a lack of available housing supply. The government of the United Kingdom is actively working on building policies to address the same issues that the United States government is also concerned about.

    Additionally, the United Kingdom has a similar political system when compared to the United States. The United Kingdom is also a democracy that elects its leaders, though it is a parliamentary democracy rather than a democratic republic like the U.S. This means that whichever party elects the most candidates get to choose the leader and will make the policies. In the United States, our system elects the leader separately, so the common situation of Congress and the President disagreeing and having to compromise on policy does not happen in the UK. It is easier to get policy passed and enacted in the United Kingdom and thus there is little motivation for elected officials to compromise on the design of policy and programs, whereas U.S. housing policy is often a product of political compromise. The United Kingdom has a developed post-industrial economy like the United States. While it has more social welfare policies to assist citizens who experience poverty, it still has an expansive, powerful private market.. 

    The UK also executes its housing policy in a similar way as the United States in that they are mainly administered at the local level. Local governments have a strong influence on housing policy in both countries. British cities also have strict zoning regulations like most American cities, and these uncompromising laws can limit the amount of housing that can be built.

    Housing History and Policies in the United Kingdom

    Like the United States, the United Kingdom experienced a housing boom after World War II, though for different reasons. The United States government provided low interest and guaranteed mortgage loans for returning soldiers that made homeownership accessible for the first time for millions of Americans. The United Kingdom instead focused on rebuilding the housing that had been destroyed during the war. Given the rise in popularity of socialist policies in post-war Britain, such as establishing a national healthcare system and the nationalization of important industries, the post-war government ultimately built over four million publicly owned housing units. These housing units had reduced rent rates for residents and, in the decades following the war, were referred to as “social housing” or “council housing.” The UK built a diverse range of housing types, while the United States focused on high rise building for social housing. At its peak in the 1970s, 33% of United Kingdom citizens lived in social housing.

    When Margaret Thatcher assumed the role of prime minister in 1979, her more ideologically conservative government began privatizing many of the post-war government-controlled industries. Her government implemented a policy referred to as “right-to-buy” for Britain’s social housing. If a household rented a social housing unit for two years, they would then be able to purchase the unit at a steep discount. While it provided an easy transition to homeownership on affordable terms for low income households, the government has not been replacing the social housing at the same rate that units are being purchased. This policy has remained in place since its implementation by the Thatcher government and while it has helped raise the homeownership rate in the United Kingdom, it has also limited the amount of social housing units available for rent for today’s low-income households.

    Modern housing policy in the United Kingdom has focused on increasing demand for housing rather than policies that increase the supply of housing. In 2013, the UK government under David Cameron created homeownership loan programs that offered favorable mortgage terms. While the goal of this policy was to encourage private developers to build more housing and increase the overall homeownership rate, there ultimately was no increase in home construction but an increase in the price of housing as more households were demanding housing as homeownership became more attainable through these programs. The current government, led by Boris Johnson, has targeted the strict zoning regulations in the UK as a reason for the declining homeownership rate and the increasingly unaffordable price of housing. His government has loosened government regulations on local planning and zoning, but the effects have yet to be seen. 

    What can the United States learn from Housing Policy in the United Kingdom?

    The United Kingdom has historically had a larger government presence in the housing markets through the construction of abundant social housing following World War II. While many social housing units are now privately owned, 17% of British households live in social housing today. Comparatively, less than 1% of Americans live in public housing today. Even with this amount of regulated rent units, there is still a thriving private market for housing. The United Kingdom currently has a 70% homeownership rate, higher than the United States’ rate of 65%. The current state of housing in the United Kingdom suggests that a developed country can have a significant amount of government owned and regulated housing units for low-income households while still having a large amount of private real estate. 

    Additionally, the United States could consider the policies of diversifying the types of public housing available, loosening zoning restrictions to allow for the construction of more housing, and implementing a version of a “right-to-buy” policy for public housing residents. Americans considering changes in national housing policy should also consider whether the government influencing the supply of housing or the government influencing the demand for housing will be more successful. While supply-based housing policies, such as the UK’s social housing program, are historically more effective, they are usually more costly than policies that affect the demand for housing. United States housing policy has focused on influencing the demand for housing, with millions of families being able to purchase homes with favorable mortgage loans from the US government and with Section 8 vouchers but could consider beginning to favor supply-based housing policies, such as increasing the amount of public housing units available or increasing the funds available for private developers of affordable housing. 

  • Historical Context for U.S. Housing Policy Part 1: The New Deal Era

    Historical Context for U.S. Housing Policy Part 1: The New Deal Era

    The HOLC and the FHA

    The core pieces of legislation that make up current American housing policy began in the New Deal era. The wreckage wrought by the Great Depression led to widespread poverty and foreclosures. The moment was right for major steps to alleviate suffering. President Franklin Delano Roosevelt entered office on a tide of Democratic power, spawned by widespread agreement that the Hoover administration was to blame for the regulatory mistakes which caused the Depression. In 1933, the Home Owners Loan Corporation (HOLC) was established to bail out defaulting home buyers by trading government bonds for delinquent mortgages. 

    The HOLC was accompanied by a set of federal agencies which were created to stimulate the housing market, the foremost of which was the Federal Housing Administration (FHA). Created in 1934, the FHA provides mortgage insurance for loans that adhere to an established set of requirements, effectively protecting against default, encouraging longer terms, larger sums of money, lower interest rates, and stricter construction standards. The FHA joined and was bolstered by the mortgage interest deduction, or the MID, which came into being in 1913, not to spur homeownership but as part of a general policy allowing businesses to deduct interest payments from loans. 

    With the introduction of “mass tax” in the mid-1930s, the MID began to make an enormous impact. Joined by the HOLC and the FHA, it allowed homeowners to deduct vast amounts of money from their taxed income—money that they were pouring into expensive new mortgages. Without federal insurance, it would make little financial sense for banks to offer loans on such a scale because of the high costs of developing and maintaining housing. Additionally, the MID allowed homeowners to accumulate vast amounts of equity on their homes over the 25 years or so that they committed to pay off their mortgage. Moreover, homeowners could refinance their mortgage to extract equity to finance further purchases, thus operating as a forced savings mechanism that accelerated wealth at unprecedented rates. 

    When speaking of “generational wealth” in this country, the MID is the key mechanism at work. However, the benefits of the three-pronged support provided by the MID, the FHA, and the HOLC were not enjoyed by everyone. Numerous historians have documented the myriad ways in which a combination of FHA policy (which has come to be known as “redlining”) and localized racism excluded Black Americans from good mortgages in up and coming neighborhoods. Under the ostensibly profit-driven justification that Black Americans were uniformly at “higher risk of default,” the FHA maintained mortgage underwriting standards that described “the infiltration of inharmonious racial or nationality groups” as a central factor in creating unstable neighborhoods.

    The MID is currently by far the largest government subsidy directed at homeowners. It is also highly popular and enjoys support from a wide constituency, particularly business class elites and people who hold political sway. This is not surprising, as the subsidy applies only to homeowners who itemize their deductions, which is primarily middle- and high-income households; thus, rich families accrue the majority of the subsidy. Many advocates for the MID argue that it encourages homeownership, which has been shown to have numerous positive “spillover effects” through its creation of stable neighborhoods of consistent socioeconomic status. 

    G.I. Bill

    As the MID and FHA programs began to gain traction with the American public, a second major policy initiative developed in Congress. The G.I. Bill of 1948 welcomed World War II veterans home from war with a sweetened version of the mortgage subsidy offered to other Americans. There was widespread consensus among policymakers that veterans returning home should receive political priority. The American Legion, a conservative and patriotic organization, introduced a set of proposals to Congress which included medical care, unemployment insurance, four-year college education, furlough pay, and home, and farm mortgages.

    Once passed, the G.I. Bill enabled lengthy mortgages with even smaller interest rates and no down payments. The program ultimately fell under the jurisdiction of the Veterans Administration (VA), which, with veterans’ interests in mind, instituted broad safety nets for default and foreclosure. Each year from 1950 to 1960, an average of 200,000 first time homebuyers were financed through the GI bill, which exceeded the number financed by the booming FHA program. The GI bill helped to create a stable and well-housed middle class, primarily located in suburbs and in urban neighborhoods composed of predominantly single-family homes. The policies were also friendly to banks and developers who were able to proceed with reckless abandon—buoyed by the sturdy backing of the federal policies. Absent a racial lens, the GI bill registers as a resounding note of success. However, recent attention has been given to racially discriminatory policies in the bill. Black Americans returning home from Europe were systematically denied entrance into the mortgage program—a move which is often contextualized as a necessary compromise with stingy Southern Democrats in Congress. While operating to improve the quality of life for many Americans, the GI Bill further expanded the gap between White and Black Americans by denying Black Americans a valuable wealth building tool. 

  • Environmental Regulation and Housing Affordability

    Environmental Regulation and Housing Affordability

    Environmental regulations are laws, imposed by the federal or local government, to mediate between natural systems and human systems, often with the intent to improve and preserve ecosystems and safeguard human health. Environmental regulations influence the supply and control the uses of developable land by restricting land use, regulating sources of pollution, and setting aside land for the protection of vulnerable ecosystems and species. Environmental laws also provide pathways for citizens to participate in decisions that affect their community through public comments, public hearings, and citizen lawsuits. Regulatory processes and requirements imposed by environmental laws can increase the cost of building and reduce the supply of available housing, thus increasing housing prices. 

    Housing Affordability

    Environmental laws that impact housing supply and affordability include:

    Environmental regulations pose challenges to tackling housing affordability and insecurity issues. Housing affordability is determined in part by the cost of housing, which incorporates building costs, financing costs, operating costs, and supply of housing. Environmental regulations largely impact the building, operating, and supply components. Building costs vary with the availability of land and the ease of development. Laws such as wetlands regulations can limit the land available for development. Furthermore, construction creates pollutants that must be mitigated, creating additional building costs. Environmental regulations often impose restrictions on water usage, waste management, and energy use, increasing utilities fees and operation costs. Low-income housing is disproportionately affected because homes tend to be older and less efficient, and there is little money to spend on repairing or replacing inefficient systems. Additionally, environmental laws allow citizens to sue government agencies if they believe a law has not been adequately enforced, but the threat of these lawsuits can discourage developers from proposing new projects. If lawsuits do occur, they can delay construction, create additional costs, and sometimes stop projects altogether. Finally, environmental regulations more frequently apply to federal agencies than private organizations or companies. While most public housing projects are subject to environmental regulations, private projects that do not involve federal funding, work, or permits are usually unaffected. Thus, environmental regulations might create an additional challenge for public housing projects.

    Arguments for Strict Environmental Regulations

    Individuals who advocate for strict environmental regulations argue that strong environmental regulations protect people, especially low-income communities and people of color, from environmental burdens caused by development projects. Environmental regulations ensure that developers’ and businesses’ actions are environmentally and socially conscious since the most cost-effective and convenient actions often involve environmental externalities. Additionally, locally unwanted land uses such as landfills, oil wells, and manufacturing facilities are disproportionately sited in low-income communities of color. Environmental laws require agencies to invite public comments on environmental impact statements, giving communities input into the location of these projects. They also allow citizens to file lawsuits against an agency if they fail to uphold the law, providing the public with an important legal tool to combat pollution and environmental burdens in their neighborhoods. 

    Some researchers and studies indicate the impact of environmental regulation as a barrier to development is overstated. Compared to the number of projects subject to environmental regulations, relatively few are litigated. In some cases, environmental assessments can save money by discouraging impractical projects or revealing environmental issues that can be solved before construction begins. Strict regulations also encourage companies to develop and improve sustainable technologies, making those technologies more accessible and less expensive.

    Arguments for Streamlined Environmental Regulations

    Others argue that environmental regulations should be streamlined to reduce the cost and timeline of development projects. Environmental impact reports, which are often required by environmental regulations, increase the time, cost, and uncertainty of getting a construction project approved. Additionally, land-use restrictions, pollution screening and mitigation, and utility fees imposed by environmental laws increase the building and carrying costs of housing. The threat of litigation over environmental concerns can deter developers from starting housing projects, and if a developer is sued they will likely face extensive project delays, expensive litigation costs, and environmental review fees. Since any member of the public can file a citizen suit to enforce environmental laws, locals have abused this tool to prevent unpopular development projects, including affordable housing, from being built in their communities. Environmental regulations do not often consider socioeconomic inequality, and this can disproportionately affect housing affordability for low-income communities. Regulations and environmental policies encourage developers or landlords to upgrade energy systems, install new windows, or update appliances to be more energy efficient. However, this increases home values and puts those units out of reach of low-income tenants.

    Questions to Consider:

    Many factors contribute to this debate, including the need for healthy communities, environmental justice, affordable housing, a greater supply of housing, and protections for ecosystems and species. 

    • Should exceptions to environmental regulations be made to increase the viability of affordable housing projects? 
    • Can environmental laws be simplified to reduce housing insecurity and improve the quality of life for low-income individuals without jeopardizing the health of disadvantaged communities? 
    • Finally, should we sacrifice environmental protections to streamline development, or can other measures be equally, or more effective in improving the housing crisis?
  • Promoting homeownership and supporting renters?

    Promoting homeownership and supporting renters?

    A source of debate within U.S. housing policy is whether the federal government should favor policies that promote homeownership or policies that support renters. In the United States, homeownership and renting are targeted by our existing housing policies, but which area should be favored by policymakers? With a limited amount of federal funding available, policymakers must weigh the benefits and drawbacks of investing in homeownership or rental as they make policy.

    Supporting Homeownership

    Recent federal budgets have spent twice as much on programs supporting renters than those supporting homeownership. Policymakers have traditionally favored policies that build homeownership such as guaranteeing mortgage payments to lenders through the Federal Housing Administration and the mortgage interest deduction because owning a home is the main form of wealth building in the United States. Homeownership can help American families purchase property that is likely to steadily increase in value over time and that can be passed down to the next generation. The passing of wealth through generations gives future Americans a financial step up and creates upward economic mobility. Ideally, this generational cycling of wealth will give the future family the financial means to purchase their own home, invest in businesses, or use it to attend college. Owning a home does not only increase the wealth of the owner themselves, but also has long term economic impacts on society. Making homeownership more accessible to more people can improve the wealth of present and future households and benefit the U.S. government through increased tax revenue, a more educated population, and decreased use of social welfare programs.

    Supporting homeownership policies also has short term economic benefits for other households seeking to purchase a home. The federal government runs two publicly owned enterprises called Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae that sell government assisted mortgages to private lenders and then reinvest the profit in federal housing programs. These programs actually turn a profit for the federal government who then uses that profit to support more Americans in purchasing a home. There is no comparable economic multiplier when it comes to programs supporting renters where the government can recover the money spent on renters.

    Those in favor of prioritizing homeownership in housing policy also see these policies as a way to address the wealth gap in the United States between White and Black households. As Black households were often excluded from past government efforts to build homeownership, White households gained wealth over time while Black households did not have the same opportunity for economic mobility. Today in the United States, there is a 30 percent gap between the homeownership rate of White households and Black households. A gap of this size has not occurred in the U.S. since racial discrimination in housing was outlawed by the Fair Housing Act of 1968. Government investment in policies that increase the homeownership rate, especially the homeownership rate in communities of color, can build generational wealth in communities that were historically excluded from government support in wealth building through homeownership. Given that homeownership is the main form of wealth building for most Americans, assisting Americans in achieving homeownership could be a policy choice for policymakers interested in wealth and income equity.

    Supporting Renters

    Proponents of increasing funding for federal policies that support renter households point to several economic trends that have made homeownership an unrealistic expectation for every American household. Median home prices increased 121 percent nationwide since 1960, but the median household income only increased by 29 percent. Owning a home is no longer affordable for many American households as they simply do not have the income to support a down payment, monthly mortgage payments, and home repairs. The Millennial generation of Americans are 8 percent less likely to own homes compared to other generations at the same age. The generation that is at the prime age of entering homeownership is instead staying in the rental market because of cost, decreasing the U.S. homeownership rate for the first time in decades. The lackluster growth in household income has kept millions of households in the rental market. Investing in policies targeting renters can support households that do not have the economic opportunity to own a home as that trend becomes more common. Policies targeting homeownership would eat up money as homes become more expensive, making rental-based policies seem more reasonable to policymakers.

    Renters are more likely to be low income households, while homeowners are more likely to be middle or high income. Many feel that government programs should prefer aiding low income Americans to middle or high. In 2019, the median household income for households that owned their homes was around $84,000, whereas the median household income for households that were renting was around $46,000. Equity advocates also point to the fact that renting households are disproportionately households of color. These are households who may have not had access to generational wealth to own a home in the first place and they rent because it is their only option. Without generational wealth to support a down payment, additional investment, or higher education to earn a higher income, many renter households will not be able to transition to homeownership without significant financial aid. In the short term, it would be more equitable to subsidize their rent than try to entice them with current homeownership programs that still require participants to be able to put up a down payment on their own and mortgage payments without a subsidy that accounts for their low-income. Investment in renter-focused policies will help low-income households and households of color secure quality affordable housing rather than give subsidies to high income households.

    Moreover, renting can still provide families with safe, quality, affordable housing while being realistic about the hidden costs of homeownership. Also, even if the federal government helps low-income Americans access mortgage loans with better terms that fit their income, there is no government intervention for necessary repairs, which are more likely to happen to homes priced in the range of what a low-income household could afford, and improvement costs to maintain the home’s value. Even if a low-income household becomes able to purchase a home, that home will most likely not build as much equity as a home owned by a high income household, repeating the cycle of poverty as low income homeowners do not recoup their investments and deal with hidden costs of homeownership

    In addition to inequities in homeownership in terms of income access, there are also large racial inequities in the valuation of homes owned by Black households. For Black households that do purchase a home, they can also face a smaller appreciation of home value because of how homes are appraised. Homes in majority-Black neighborhoods were valued on average $48,000, or 23% less than those with few or no Black residents, even when controlling for differences in schools, crime, and other neighborhood characteristics. In some cases, low income and/or Black households will be able to purchase a home, but they still may not reap the benefits of homeownership that homeownership policies are intended to create. They are less likely to build generational wealth through homeownership compared to white and/or high-income households, and so, the federal government should instead be more realistic about homeownership as a panacea to all housing and income inequality issues in the United States. Supporting renters acknowledges the reality of the U.S. housing market and existing inequities in homeownership while still helping Americans attain quality, affordable, and stable housing.

    Questions to Consider:

    • Currently, there is limited funding appropriated for housing policy. Should the federal government focus on increasing access to homeownership or supporting renter households? Which is a better use of federal money?
    • Which policies seem more realistic given past and current trends in housing?
    • Which policies are more equitable and will help address existing disparities in the United States?
    • Which policies would be more politically popular and thus more likely to receive support from policymakers?
  • The History of Housing Policy in the United States

    The History of Housing Policy in the United States

    Contemporary housing policies in the United States have evolved from major economic events in the 20th century. The Great Depression marked the start of these catalysts as the worst economic emergency in the United States hit the housing market first. In the 1930s social welfare programs were limited and wages were lower, partially due to weak labor unions. Once the stock market crashed in 1929, President Hoover and his successor, President Roosevelt, had to reconcile with the housing crisis and create new government institutions to resolve these issues–the first of their kind.

    The 1930s

    The biggest housing issues for low-income Americans were the substandard conditions of the housing stock and lack of access to home ownership for low-income families. Homeownership was less of a priority and being a tenant was more socially acceptable, as financing a house was out of reach for most low-income Americans. Congress passed the Emergency Relief and Construction Act of 1932, which created the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC), allowing banks to lend to private corporations that provide housing for low-income households. In the same year, President Hoover implemented the Home Loan Bank System, which consisted of twelve Federal Home Loan Banks and a Federal Home Loan Board. The Home Owners Loan Corporation essentially bailed out defaulting home buyers by trading government bonds for bad mortgages. However, Hoover’s new system was outpaced by growing unemployment and home ownership continued to decrease to two-fifths of all households in 1933. 

    The National Housing Act passed in 1934 under FDR formed the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) with the mission to improve housing conditions by providing credit for home repairs and home purchases. Insurance policies of the FHA allowed for mortgage loans to be paid monthly, forming a secondary market for home mortgages. The FHA was reported to have helped 12 million people improve their living conditions, but this number ignores the discriminatory lending practices called redlining, a system the FHA and the Home Owners’ Loan Corporation used to grade the profitability of neighborhoods. The four categories were green (“best”), blue (“still desirable”), yellow (“definitely declining”), and red (hazardous). These grades were largely based on the neighborhood’s racial, ethnic, socioeconomic, and religious composition. White, middle-class neighborhoods received FHA loans whereas Black and Hispanic neighborhoods were deemed hazardous and declining in value and did not receive FHA insured mortgages or loans. Redlining continues to impact the intergenerational wealth of Black and Hispanic Americans due to these discriminatory zoning and lending practices. 

    Congress had first pushed to introduce public housing in 1933 on a trial basis. This was encouraged from outside of the administration by activists and scholars. The United States Housing Act of 1937 solidified public housing and created the United States Housing Authority to administer the program. This bill allocated federal subsidies to local housing authorities to improve the conditions of low-income housing. The same top-down system is used today. The USHA created the regulations for construction costs, limits on tenant incomes, and architecture for local authorities to follow. Public housing became standardized to fit these stipulations, and low-income housing became distinguishable across the country by the monotonous brick-laid buildings. 

    In 1938, the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae) was created by Congress as a subsidiary of the RFC. It was implemented to stimulate construction for housing. Fannie Mae backed loans in the secondary mortgage market but did not directly lend to homeowners. Its sibling program, the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac), was chartered in 1970 to continue money flow into the mortgage market. The purpose of Freddie Mac is to also stimulate homeownership and rentals for middle-income Americans. 

    The 1940s

    After World War II, the United States faced another housing crisis as millions of veterans returned home from overseas. There was a lack of available housing for the influx of people and President Roosevelt was forced to address the housing shortage. The Servicemen’s Readjustment Act passed (also known as the G.I. Bill) in 1944 and created programs to support returning veterans of World War II. This included mortgages and loans at low interest rates but were denied to Black veterans. The G.I. Bill was extremely beneficial for those included in its assistance but also perpetuated the unjust housing policies that harmed Black Americans and other minority groups. 

    The 1950s

    The Housing Act of 1954 provided funding to construction, demolition, rehabilitation, and conservation of decaying neighborhoods. This new effort arose from the booming economy that followed the war-torn previous decade. Urban renewal became the new focus of federal housing initiatives, especially in inner cities. Sections 203 and 207 of the Housing Act of 1956 gave priority to the elderly and paid those displaced by urban renewal. The Federal Highway Act was passed in 1956 which chartered the construction of an interstate highway that bulldozed “blighted neighborhoods” and impacted low-income communities the most. Highways encouraged white flight from urban centers into suburban areas. This is the start of visualizing the “American Dream” in terms of white picket fences and suburbia. 

    The 1960s 

    In 1968, President Johnson signed the Civil Rights Act which included the Fair Housing Act (FHA). The FHA protected citizens from discrimination when buying or renting a home and increased protections for those seeking federally funded housing. This bill also outlawed practices like blockbusting which was a common practice where real estate agents would convince  White home owners to sell their homes before Black Americans moved into their neighborhoods and decreased property values. The FHA eventually formed the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) at the cabinet level. The mission of HUD was to assist homeownership, community development, and affordable housing through federal programs. HUD continues to be the major agency of housing in the U.S.

    The 1980s

    President Reagan cut more than 50 percent of HUD’s budget, dropping from $83.6 billion in 1976 to $40 billion in 1982. He then implemented the Low-Income Housing Tax Credit (LIHTC) in 1986. With this program, banks and private companies can purchase federal income tax credits and use profits to build affordable housing. This continues to be the primary source of funding for affordable housing today. Section 8 Housing Choice Voucher Programs were added to the Housing Act of 1937 in 1974 and continue to aid extremely low-income households. Vouchers allow tenants to pay 30 percent of income towards rent while the rest is covered by federal subsidies. Despite the success of vouchers for recipients, the waitlist for Section 8 vouchers is often multiple years long and many landlords refuse to rent to people with vouchers. 

    The 1990s to 2008

    In 1992, Congress implemented the HOPE VI program to focus on urban revitalization. This provided block grants for low-rise and mixed-income housing to combat previous histories of public housing and segregated socioeconomic neighborhoods. Unfortunately, many cities that receive these funds use it to destroy slums and implement private housing. In 2007, the housing market crashed and forced 3 million foreclosures over the following three years. The U.S. continues to rebuild the housing market over a decade after the crash. The history of housing in the U.S. proves the ever changing social and political context of affordability and access, and where contemporary issues develop. 

  • Intro to Rent Control

    Intro to Rent Control

    The term ‘housing crisis’ encompasses many different issues, including housing affordability, affordable rental housing, lending standards, and housing value. According to the National Low Income Housing Coalition, there is a housing shortage of 7.2 million homes in the United States. Affordable housing is any housing unit that can be afforded (requiring up to 30% of total income) by those below the median household income. One way to make housing more affordable and accessible to low-income households is through rent control laws.

    Rent control laws are legislation placing a limit on rental rates in a city or a state. Rent control varies by location, but it generally states a maximum amount of rent that can be charged for a unit, as well as the amount that the rent can be increased by per year. The specific numbers vary based on local inflation and cost of living, and it is largely influenced by political party divisions and politicking. These laws are intended to keep living costs affordable for lower-income citizens and regulate the housing market. 

    Rent control laws ensure that rent is priced below market-rate housing. The lower price of rent-controlled apartments makes housing affordable, especially in neighbourhoods with a high median price. This causes several main benefits:

    • Education: One cause of systemic poverty is the quality of education. This paper by Servaas Van Der Berg et al. explains how “the low quality of tuition offered in schools in poor communities can entrench exclusion and marginalisation.” By artificially lowering rent costs, lower-income families are able to live in higher quality school districts and safer neighbourhoods, breaking cycles of poverty. 
    • Stability: Since rent controlled units are affordable and have predictable pricing long-term, they have lower turnover rates than other units. A neighbourhood with long-lasting tenants will build a sense of community and camaraderie. Residents are more invested in the safety and prosperity of their neighbourhood. This article from the Urban Institute explains how constant moving impacts education, social and political capital, health, financial security, and the level of safety and crime in a neighbourhood. This study by Dr. Oshi concludes that children who move repeatedly in their childhood report more behavioural problems and poorer academic performance. 
    • Ending “No-Cause Evictions”: Rent control laws have included language that will protect tenants from evictions without cause. Currently, these laws do not exist on a federal level and landlords have the ability to evict tenants without cause (“no-cause evictions”). Since the main tenants for rent-control units are the elderly and low-income families, rent control laws will allow these tenants to live without the fear of a sudden rent increase by ensuring that rent is increased by a set amount each year. Reducing the number of no-cause evictions also increase neighbourhood stability and community.

    Overall, rent control allows lower-income renters to achieve greater levels of stability and protects them from individual landlord decisions about price by delegating these decisions to local legislators.

    The longer a unit is rent controlled, the further the rent will fall behind market-price. Because tenants are paying cheaper prices for each unit, the landlords make less profit per unit than they otherwise would without the rent control policy. This causes several main drawbacks: 

    • Poor Apartment Maintenance: in non-rent control apartments, landlords generally upgrade unit appliances every few years to make units more appealing to potential tenants. If landlords make less money from rent-controlled units, they will have to spend less on maintenance and upgrades to keep the same profit. 
    • Rising Rent Costs: landlords will likely offset the decreased profits from rent-controlled units by raising the prices on their market-rate units. This artificially increases the rent-price in a certain area, making the area unaffordable for low and moderate-income families. 
    • Decreased Housing Supply: developers are not incentivized to build new buildings in rent controlled areas because developers often intend to price newly-built units at or above market rate for the area. With rent prices below market rate, developers won’t turn profits on new builds for years, and they will skip over rent-controlled markets in favour of freer markets.

    (More information on the pros and cons of rent control)

    Case Study: Berlin

    Berlin experienced a drastic increase in rental rates, which spurred three of Berlin’s leftist parties to enact a five-year rent control freeze. This is an unusual policy; most rent control policies restricts rental increase and have no set time period. The policy stated that rent for all apartments built before 2014 are frozen at their June 2019 price for the next 5 years, which applies to 90% of Berlin’s available housing units. This decision encourages new builds, as they will not fall under the rent control policy. 

    This split Berlin’s available housing into two markets: the 90% of rent-capped units and the smaller market of unregulated units built after 2014. The average rental price for rent-capped apartments plummeted when compared to other major European cities; the average rental price for the smaller unregulated market soared. Since the supply of non-regulated apartment buildings is so slim, and landlords are looking to make up the costs incurred from their rent-controlled apartments, the rent for newly built apartment buildings are now even more unaffordable for new tenants. With young people still flocking to Berlin, and a lack of movement in apartment units, there is a sharp decline of regulated apartments available for new tenants. 

    Berlin’s housing market is seeing the effects of this policy only a year later with a substantial increase in median rental price on apartments. According to Bloomberg, the rent in Berlin’s regulated apartments (90% of units) grew at -57.7% (March 31st, 2021) relative to the growth in the 13 next-largest cities in Germany. The rent in Berlin’s unregulated apartments (10% of units) grew 8.8% (March 31st, 2021) relative to the growth in the 13 next-largest cities in Germany. (More information about Berlin’s policy and the one-year analysis available here, here, and here)

    Conclusion

    Those in favour of rent control believe that the benefits of affordable rent today outweigh the long-term negative impact on the rental economy. They believe that landlords should not be able to increase rent by large amounts each year. Rent control laws give more power to the tenants. Those opposed to rent control argue that artificially low rental rates result in lower-condition housing, which decreases living standards overall. They believe the current units will become dilapidated and new units will not be built, resulting in a housing shortage crisis in the near future. 

    The Berlin case study sheds light on the immediate effects of rent control policy on the housing market. This policy was more aggressive than usual rent control laws, so it’s hard to conclude what exactly the impact of rent control laws will be in the long run.

    Rent control is one of the many policy tools city council members can use to make housing more affordable; it should not be considered in isolation. Other policies, including government subsidies and mortgage interest deductions, can work with existing rent control policies to create a multi-pronged approach to affordable housing.